Trade openness and relative advantage led growth theory
According to the trade openness and comparative advantage led growth theory based on Richardian and the elementary neoclassical trade model, a region or country concentrating on different productivity would improve trade and development potential. Thus, the relative advantage is at the core of the neoclassical trade model, whether driven by technology or factor endowment, in the Ricardian model developed by Banerjee et al. (1998) and (Abhijit et al. (1993) that, supposing there is a variety of distinct factors in the economy, then assumption 0 is generally valid. Therefore, this research maintains the assumption 0, which allows expressing aggregate output under an efficient allocation. Supposing that assumption 0 holds C = 1, …C (growth) and S = 1. …, S (trade openness), aggregate output under an efficient allocation is given by exogenous vectors,
$$\vartheta \left({\sigma }^{s}{\gamma }^{c}\right)=\int \pi ({\sigma }^{s},{\gamma }^{c}) \delta \left(\omega ,{\sigma }^{s},{\gamma }^{c}\right)f\left(\omega ,{\gamma }^{c}\right)\mathcal{d}\mu \left(\omega \right) \left(1\right)$$
Where \(\pi ({\sigma }^{s},{\gamma }^{c})\) is the set of factors allocated to sectors in the economy (c).
$$\pi \left({\sigma }^{s},{\gamma }^{c}\right)=\left\{\frac{\omega ϵ\pi }{\tau \left(\omega ,{\sigma }^{s},{\gamma }^{c}\right)}>{}_{{s}^{\text{'}}\ne s}{}^{max}\tau \left(\omega ,{\sigma }^{s},{\gamma }^{c}\right)\right\} \left(2\right)$$
This research essentially refers to an economy where equations (1) and (2) hold as an elementary neoclassical economy. Therefore, in a developed form after modifications, the factor productivity or relative advantage lead growth is as follows;
$$\alpha =f\left(\sigma ,\gamma \right)=h\left(\omega \right)\alpha \left(\sigma ,\gamma \right) \left(3\right)$$
Where \(h\left(\omega \right)>0 \text{a}\text{n}\text{d} \alpha \left(\sigma ,\gamma \right)\ge 0 \left(\text{e}\text{x}\text{o}\text{g}\text{e}\text{n}\text{o}\text{u}\text{s} \text{v}\text{e}\text{c}\text{t}\text{o}\text{r}\text{s}\right)\). \(\alpha\) is a function of \(\sigma \text{a}\text{n}\text{d} \gamma ,\) trade openness, government expenditure and investment infrastructure may be relatively more productive for economic growth. If a factor \(\omega\) becomes effective as an element \(\omega\) in a given sector, then (trade openness, government expenditure and investment infrastructure) has relative advantage in the country’s economic growth.
Causal relationship between trade openness, government expenditures, investment infrastructure and economic growth
Most established theoretical literature from developed and developing countries is scant on trade openness, focusing on the relative advantage of inclusive infrastructural development and government expenditure on economic growth. Likewise, this study will review the assumption that; trade openness, government expenditure and infrastructure investment influences economic growth.
Many developing and developed countries now have a relative advantage to spike development and contribute to economic growth. It can generate employment, productivity, and domestic trade, increase government revenue or income and enhance infrastructural development. In Nigeria, Wafure et al. (2010) detected the role of foreign trade and skills acquisition on economic growth based on provision of developmental capital and relative market size advantage. Policy implied that expansion of GDP through infrastructure drives productivity due to relative market size opportunity. Gohou et al. (2012), in Africa, examined the relationship between foreign trade and poverty reduction as the human development confirmed mixed results among the developing countries. Although, foreign trade exerted positive and strongly significant relationships on the economy particularly welfare or relative advantage of human capital development. The policy suggested that international development priorities encourage labour-intensive and pro-poor sectors such as human capital and infrastructural development. Onifade et al. (2020) that government expenditure impacts economic growth applied the ARDL approach and data from 1981 to 2017. The empirical results revealed a significant relationship between government spending and economic development. Further, the result of Granger causality indicated public expenditure Granger caused real growth in the economy. The policy implied that the government should ensure that the share of public expenditure (fiscal) is kept within the reasonable budget proposal earmarked.
Osakwe et al. (2018) explored the relationship between trade libralization and export diversification in developing countries. The results indicated that developing countries trade is related to diversification in the short term and leads to economic growth. The policy implication encouraged human capital development, and institutions (infrastructure) may play a vital role in export diversification. Dudzevičiūtė et al. (2018) estimated the relationship between government spending and economic growth of European Union Countries (EU) by employing correlation and Granger causality test data from 1995 to 2015. The results showed that government spending has a significant relationship with economic growth. Unidirectional causality running from government spending to economic growth explains the role of relative human capital development in accelerating the GDP to economic growth. The policy suggested government expenditure as a growth factor should be adequately managed and efficiently allocated for development reasons. Mazorodze (2018) assessed the impact of government expenditure on economic growth from 1994 to 2016 by employing a cointegration test, VAR model estimation and Granger causality in Bangladesh. The results revealed a unidirectional causality from economic development to expenditure. The policy suggested that a rigorous strategy for monitoring the implementation of the budget would enhance human capital development relative to a change in the economy.
Ngouhouo et al. (2021) examined trade openness, and economic growth in Sub-Sahara African countries focused on the role played by domestic institutions from 1996–2017. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) results revealed that domestic institutions as a composite index determined trade openness significantly impacts on economic growth. The policy implications suggested that different states of sub-Sahara Africa should improve the quality of domestic institutions in elaborating their international trade policies. Chen et al. (2022) study that foreign trade, energy and economic growth have multiplied and are extraordinary in china. The results from 2005 to 2018 in panel data revealed that foreign trade affects energy through the export route, while the effect of the import route is not significant on growth. The policy suggested that the government should play an active role in opening trade and economic growth due to the control over energy intensity flow. Trade openness, capital formation and export are key elements to bring sustainable economic growth in a country (Zaman et al., 2021). They employed annual data to estimate the impact of IT exports, gross capital formation, FDI and trade openness on sustainable growth from 2013 to 2018. The two-step GMM technique and the results show that FDI and gross capital formation substantially positively impact economic growth. In contrast, IT exports and trade openness have a negative, insignificant impact. The policy implies that most developing countries need to invest in industrialization and encourage export-based growth.
Roşoiu (2015) used quarterly data from 1998 to 2014 to analyze the impact of government expenditures, revenues and economic growth. The results indicated granger causality through cointegration between the variables. The policy suggested using government expenditure as a means to control economic growth. government expenditure as an essential instrument for achieving full employment and improved living standard and economic growth (Ugochukwu & Oruta, 2021). Employed data from 1981 to 2020 using error correction and the Granger causality model. The results revealed government expenditures have an insignificant negative impact on economic growth. The policy suggested that the government increase and improve internally generated revenue to supplement government spending and strict monitoring of government projects. Arvin et al. (2021) measured government expenditure, tax revenue and economic growth from 2005 to 2015 using primary data in low-income and lower-middle-income countries. The short-run and long-run results show government expenditure and tax revenue have an endogenous link in the short-run. At the same time, policy implies that more vital institutions and more effective fiscal policies can sustain long-run economic growth. Nayak et al. (2021) explored the relationship between government expenditure and economic growth. The results show no relationship among the variables indicating negative impact. The policy suggested that the government should invest in the development of infrastructure to increase internal revenue generation. In Romania Popescu et al. (2021) examined government spending and economic growth by employing quarterly data from 1995 to 2020 to measure the relationship and Granger causality. The results indicated long-run relationships among the variables, and the Granger causality runs between the variables in the short run. The policy suggested that the government should concentrate on the macroeconomic inflationary factors to enhance the sector's economic development.
Infrastructure development is essential for productivity and comparative advantage (Park, 2020). The study suggested that improved quality of infrastructure fosters comparative advantage. Ke et al. (2020) investigated infrastructure development and economic growth in China by employing the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) during the period 2007 to 2015. The results showed that infrastructure significantly contributes to growth. The policy implied that the government should support local production through infrastructural strategies to benefit from comparative advantage. In China Chin et al. (2021) measured the role of infrastructure on economic growth employed panel cointegration, Granger causality and the findings indicated long run and short run relationship, Granger causality running from infrastructure to economic growth. The policy implied that infrastructure is a worthy huge investment that enhances development. Chu et al. (2020) used panel data and examined government expenditure, and economic growth data from 1993 to 2012 based on the effects of OLS fixed and GMM techniques. The results revealed that a shift in government expenditure toward effective spending forms is associated with a high level of growth. The policy implied that spending more on welfare and human capital development would improve the relative advantage of the economy. David (2019) examined causal-effect relationships employing panel data from 2000 to 2015 in African countries. The results show a bidirectional long-run relationship between infrastructures and economic growth. The causality tests indicated a feedback causal relationship. The policy implied that African countries need to include digital communication in their infrastructure to promote economic growth.
Magazzino et al. (2021) explored the impact of infrastructure on economic growth in China, employing aggregated data from 1990 to 2017. The findings from a machine learning technique for verifying causality approach revealed that infrastructure affects economic growth. The policy implication suggested that lack of infrastructure maintenance eliminates the positive effects of investments and comparative advantage over time in the medium term. Sofuoğlu et al. (2022) explored the relationship between infrastructure (high technology) on economic growth employed the modified ordinary least square and canonical cointegration regression data from 1990 to 2019. The results indicated that infrastructure (high technology) positively impacts economic growth. The policy recommended that increasing investment on infrastructure will boost exports and development. Furthermore, the users need to be educated by the government or firm. In the study of Anakpo et al. (2022) that infrastructure (technological innovation) effect on economic growth has received significant attention for development and employs panel dynamic ordinary least square regression with annual data from 2004 to 2017 for accessing relationships. The results show infrastructure has a significant positive relationship with economic growth in the long run. The policy suggested timely intervention in infrastructure can promote economic growth. Additionally, this research explores whether the theoretical interaction (assumption) of trade openness, government expenditure and inclusive infrastructural development has a relative advantage on economic growth. Ensuring the government should implement a better trade openness and high labor-intensive policy, further enhancing economic growth.
Dudzevičiūtė et al. (2018) that many scholars have debated in theoretical and empirical relevancy of government expenditure arising for structural change in growth that government expenditures stimulated economic growth. Chin et al. (2021) that trade openness promotes economic growth, which encouraged Belt and Road initiative in China to improve investment and trade acceleration through infrastructural development that plays a focal role in sustaining comparative advantage on economic growth. Also, in China, Zhang et al. (2021) the transport infrastructure effectively influences economic growth and is essential for the government to formulate growth policies. Therefore, the relationship between trade openness, government expenditures and investment in infrastructure and economic growth have become, in recent years, the most important economic topics in both academic and policy circles from developed countries.
Further empirical studies in developing countries especially Nigeria sufficed the fact that trade openness does not determine economic growth, which indicated the absence of relative advantage due to lack of good environment and policies (Shayanewako, 2018). According to some scholars Babatunde (2018); Okolo et al. (2018) and Fauzel et al. (2015) that government expenditure and investment in infrastructure seems a waste of scarce resources. Ugochukwu et al. (2021) observed that government failure to efficiently and equitably allocate resources for social and infrastructural development are most of the reasons for government to be fully involved in the economy. Moreover, one of the instruments the government uses in regulating the economy is increasing spending to achieve macroeconomic objectives like infrastructure, employment, productivity and sustained economic development. Thus, following these empirical studies in Nigeria that uses theoretical analysis based on Heckscher-Ohlin theory, Cobb-Douglass production function, Adolf Wagner’s law and Keynesian growth model (Babatunde, 2018; Okolo et al., 2018; Omoke & Opuala–Charles, 2021; Shayanewako, 2018).
Some argued that government expenditure determined economic growth, and some supported that trade openness was an essential instrument for achieving sustainable economic development. In contrast, others refuted the assertions that infrastructure development causes economic development. In addition, there is the possibility that Nigeria, with a good and efficient policy environment, will grow faster, regardless of the changes in factors of production (government expenditure and investment in infrastructure). Second, there is another possibility that in a suitable policy environment, trade openness will translate into a relative advantage. This research has revealed the relationship between trade openness, government expenditures, and infrastructure investment on economic growth in most cases. On some occasions, increasing government expenditures on human capital development will impact economic development, while in other cases, investment in infrastructure has affected trade openness. However, sometimes both government expenditures and investment in infrastructure have caused each other and support the bidirectional approach for trade openness.