This paper hypothesizes that advertising intensity is a significant determinant of dividend policies adopted by firms in emerging markets. Our arguments are based on the assumption that advertising intensity affects dividend policy by improving not only the performance/profitability of firms, but also their information environment. Both of these factors are supposed to positively affect the dividend policies adopted by firms (La Port et al., 2000; Li and Zhao, 2008; Skinner, 2008; Farooq and Aktaruzzaman, 2020).
2.1 Adverting and its effect on firm’s performance
This paper argues that one of the major aims of undertaking the advertising activity is the improvement of firm’s performance (Farooq and Pashayev, 2020; Luo and de Jong, 2012; Joshi and Hanssens, 2009; Pauwels et al., 2004; Mizik and Jacobson, 2003; Kotabe et al., 2002). A firm that spends more resources on advertising can increase its sales by encouraging the existing customers to buy more of its products and by inducing the customers of competing firms to switch to its products. These firms can also create the competitive advantage vis-à-vis other firms by influencing the choices of customers, employees, and investors (Bick, 2009). In the process of increasing sales, a firm can also build its brand (Aaker, 1996). Wang and Sengupta (2016) argue that brand building is based on the premise that strong brands generate long-term competitive advantages for firms. Because of the strong brands, it is possible for firms to charge premium prices. It, therefore, increases and maintains the profitability of firms. Steenkamp (2014) argues that the products associated with stronger brands are more likely to sustain a price premium as compared to the products associated with weaker brands. It is for this reason that the strength of a brand is viewed as one of the most significant strategic assets (Vomberg et al., 2015).[3] Prior literature notes that brand creates competitive advantages for a firm in a number of ways (Johansson et al., 2012; Vomberg et al., 2015; Wang et al., 2015). For instance, brands may encourage customers’ repeat purchase by reducing their search cost. It may also reduce their inclination for comparison shopping. Moreover, brands may reduce the competitive pressure by making customers less susceptible to competitors’ marketing activities. Furthermore, strong brands can create long-term sustainable advantage for firms by cultivating the customer equity (Rust et al., 2005). The greater is the customer equity, the higher is the subjective assessment of the brand by customers. Johansson et al. (2012) note that customer equity positively affects customer’s satisfaction.
An obvious outcome of the above arguments is the high correlation between advertising and firm value (Yeung and Ramasamy, 2008; Kirk et al., 2013; Wang et al., 2015). Hirschey (1985), for example, reports a significantly positive relationship between the market value of a firm and its advertising expenditures. Helsen et al. (1993) also document greater likelihood of success for firms that firms undertake higher advertising activities. In another related study, Graham and Frankenberge (2000) show that changes in advertising expenditures are positively associated with changes in market values. Singh et al. (2005) confirm the above findings by reporting that firms with higher advertising expenditures experience better performance. The essence of above studies is that firms with higher advertising activities generate more profits than firms with a lower advertising activities. Kotabe et al. (2002) note that firms with extensive advertising activities can enhance their performance by targeting the customer needs and by having better bargaining power with both distributors and consumers.
Another argument that can be cited for the positive impact of adverting of firm performance is based on the assumption that advertising activities create intangible market-based assets (Srivastava et al., 1998). The intangible market-based assets consist of (among other things) brand, customer relationships, channel relationships, and partner relationships. These assets are valuable and can improve the performance/value of the firm. Sougiannis (1994) argues that investors put heavy emphasis on the valuation of intangible assets, including advertising expenditures. Kim (2008) shows that such intangible assets increase the performance of firms. Furthermore, the intangible market-based assets can improve the performance of the firms by insulating them from stock market volatility (McAlister et al., 2007). Srivastava et al. (1998) document that intangible assets, such as those created due to advertising, improve firm performance by “accelerating and enhancing cash flows, and lowering the volatility and vulnerability”.
2.2 Adverting and its effect on firm’s information environment
The real markets are characterized by imperfect information. The availability of less than perfect information leads to the deterioration of informational efficiency of these markets. Provision of information is, therefore, a very valuable and desirable trait in these markets. One of the mechanisms that can assist firms in disclosing and disseminating their information is advertising. Joshi and Hanssens (2009) maintain that advertising is important because it creates the demand not only for the products and services offered by the firms, but also for the information about these products and services. We argue that, by providing information via advertising, firms can generate interest among individuals, thereby increasing the demand for additional information about the firm.[4] Chauvin and Hirschey (1993) document that investors can use the information on advertising activities to form expectations about future cash flows. Our arguments are also supported by the actual events, such as discontinuation of information on advertising expenses by the Apple Inc. in 2016. Financial analysts and investors raised complaints about this action because they considered the information contained in the advertising expenses to be a useful. The informational value of advertising can also be judged from the stock market liquidity generated by firms that advertise heavily. Grullon et al. (2004) document that the stocks of firms that advertise are more liquid and have smaller bid-ask spreads than the stocks of other firms that do not advertise much. The argument underlying the informational role of advertising is based on the assumption that it can be used as a signaling mechanism to reduce the information gap between two entities. More specifically, firms can use advertising activities to send signals to potential investors about its growth and value. Advertising may also indicate that the firm is less risky. Allen and Faulhaber (1989) argue that firms can use mechanisms, such as advertising activities, to signal that their firm is better than other firms.[5]
2.3 Advertising and its possible impact on dividend policy
Our arguments suggest that adverting activity not only affects the performance of firms, but also affects their information environment. Plentiful of prior literature relates both of these factors with higher dividend payments (Skinner, 2008; Farooq and Aktaruzzaman, 2020). The impact of performance/profitability on dividend payments is obvious. The firms with high profitability have higher capacity to pay dividends. In fact, dividends are fundamentally determined by earnings (Skinner, 2008). The firms that generate higher earnings on a per share basis are more likely to pay higher dividends. Lee and Ryan (2002) show that current earnings are significant determinant of dividends. Furthermore, while highlighting the relationship between earnings and dividends, Damodaran (2014) notes that dividends follow earnings. He argues that managers will increase dividends only if they are sure that a permanent shift in earnings has occurred. In other words, changes in dividends depend on the level of earnings generated by firms. In another related study, Healy and Palepu (1988) show that firms initiating dividends also have positive earnings. They also show that dividend omission is preceded by two years of earnings declines that continue during the year of the omission. Lipson et al. (1998) also report similar findings by showing that firms that initiate dividends have greater earnings increases than those firms that do not initiate dividends.
The relationship between information environment of a firm and dividend policy has also generated considerable interest. Prior literature argues that better information environment curtails the ability of managers to expropriate corporate resources (La Port et al., 2000; Li and Zhao, 2008; Lin et al., 2017; Apergis and Eleftheriou, 2017). The underlying argument in this strand of literature is that better information environment makes it difficult for managers to expropriate corporate resources. In the presence of more transparent information environment, it is easier for shareholders to notice the deceitful behavior of managers. Consequently, managers are reluctant to misuse corporate resources. An outcome of this disciplining role of information environment is that managers are more likely to share higher proportion of earnings with shareholders. These arguments are supported by significant number of prior empirical studies that document low dividend payments for firms with high information asymmetries. Li and Zhao (2008), for example, find that the extent of information asymmetries – analyst earnings forecast errors and the dispersion in their forecasts – negatively affect dividend payouts. They document that firms with higher information asymmetries are less likely to pay, initiate, or increase dividends. They also show that such firms pay small dividends whenever they have to pay relative to firms with lower agency problems. Leary and Michaely (2011) also come to the same conclusion by showing that firms with higher levels of asymmetric information distribute lower dividends. Brockman and Unlu (2011) use the international sample and show that firms from countries where disclosure environments are not transparent (higher information asymmetries) pay lower dividends. More recently, Farooq and Aktaruzzaman (2020) show that firms with higher information asymmetries pay lower dividends. Above arguments lead us to hypothesize the following.[6]
Hypothesis 1:
|
There is a positive relationship between advertising expenditures and dividend payments.
|
[3] Once the brand is established, it becomes relatively inimitable and non-substitutable. This characteristic makes it very desirable for the firms to have a strong brand (Barney et al., 2001).
[4] It is possible that, due to search costs, it may be hard for some of the market participants to track the activities of firms. For such market participants, advertising can be helpful because it may disclose and disseminate some of the valuable information.
[5] The ability of advertising to create intangible market-based assets may also increase the demand for information, thereby reducing the information asymmetries. Given that valuation of intangible assets require more effort and resources, it is possible that investors and analysts increase their search for information about firms that have higher advertising activities.
[6] In contrast to the arguments presented above, there is a competing strand of literature that suggests the opposite. This strand of literature considers dividend policy as a mechanism via which firms can reduce information asymmetries. Grossman and Hart (1980), Jensen (1986), and La Porta et al. (2000) serve as good references on these arguments.