The results presented in this section are intended to give credibility to the various analyses made in the previous sections. To this end, an analysis of the basic results is presented in the first section. In the second, we test the robustness of our results.
6.1 Baseline results
To analyse the effects of government ideology on disaster prevention, we used a logit model. The application of this model requires that the dependent variable is binary. In accordance with the work of Raschky and Schwindt (2016); Tselios and Tompkins (2020) we take thevalue 1 if the country (i) has known at time (t) a natural disaster and 0 otherwise. A difficulty encountered in the implementation of binary choice models is that the coefficients derived fromthe estimates. It is recommended that marginal effects, relative risk ratios4 or even chance ratios[4] (Verbeek, 2008). In our case, it is preferable to use the odds ratios since the sample tends to be large.
Taking into account the innovative factors amounts to verifying the mediation of these factors in the relationship between government ideology and natural disaster prevention. In the table, the measure of innovation used is the number of patents. The different models in the table 2 all have an interaction term. It results from the intersection between the modality of the government’s ideology and the chosen measure of innovation. In this analysis, we focus on the coefficient of the variable (Interaction). It tells us about the sensitivity of the relationship between government ideology and natural disaster prevention.
In the tables 2 and 3 we find that the odds ratios of Right (column 1 tables 2 and 3) and Center (column 3 table 2) governments in improving disaster prevention are greater than unity. This result can be justified by the fact that governments have greater incentives to provide public goods. These can take the form of These can take the form of construction contracts and building codes, facilitating the provision of construction quality in private markets (Keefer et al., 2011). With regard to the use of patents, our results suggest that the use of patents increases the chances of each type of government to prevent natural disasters. Indeed, the coefficients associated with the patent variable are significant at the 1% level and above unity. These results are in line with those of Miao (2017). This author explains that taking technology into account in the management of the risk of natural disasters makes it possible to considerably mitigate the effects of the latter. However, a necessary condition for achieving such an objective is a considerable level of investment in the innovation sector.
Table 2
Mediating effect of the number of patents in the relationship between ideology and natural disaster prevention
Variables
|
|
Occurrence of natural disasters
|
(1)
|
(2)
|
(3)
|
(4)
|
Right
|
2.101**
(0.673)
|
|
|
|
Left
|
|
0.671
(0.165)
|
|
|
Center
|
|
|
4.234***
(2.193)
|
|
Without orientation
|
|
|
|
0.573**
(0.155)
|
Patents
|
1.329***
|
1.214***
|
1.299***
|
1.389***
|
|
(0.041)
|
(0.038)
|
(0.036)
|
(0.054)
|
Interaction
|
0.917
(0.051)
|
|
|
|
Interaction
|
|
1.284***
(0.067)
|
|
|
Interaction
|
|
|
0.890
(0.075)
|
|
Interaction
|
|
|
|
0.882**
(0.044)
|
GDP
|
0.714***
|
0.768***
|
0.740***
|
0.725***
|
|
(0.052)
|
(0.051)
|
(0.050)
|
(0.052)
|
GDP growth
|
0.995
|
0.991
|
0.994
|
0.994
|
|
(0.016)
|
(0.016)
|
(0.016)
|
(0.015)
|
Density
|
1.086*
|
1.091*
|
1.086*
|
1.127**
|
|
(0.050)
|
(0.052)
|
(0.047)
|
(0.062)
|
Human capital
|
0.615***
|
0.626***
|
0.567***
|
0.482***
|
|
(0.077)
|
(0.084)
|
(0.083)
|
(0.072)
|
Unemployment
|
0.952***
|
0.938***
|
0.952***
|
0.946***
|
|
(0.013)
|
(0.015)
|
(0.013)
|
(0.014)
|
Constant
|
12.205***
|
10.350***
|
12.294***
|
24.316***
|
|
(7.587)
|
(5.663)
|
(6.986)
|
(14.061)
|
Observations
|
1,473
|
1,473
|
1,473
|
1,473
|
Time dummy
|
yes
|
yes
|
yes
|
yes
|
Log -likelihood
|
-1013
|
-1013
|
-1013
|
-1013
|
LR Chi2
|
223.2
|
288.6
|
404.5
|
230.6
|
Prob Chi2
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
Pseudo R-squared
|
0.114
|
0.132
|
0.119
|
0.154
|
Note: The numbers in brackets represent standard deviations. ***, **, * represent the significance levels of 1 %, 5 % et 10 %. Source : Authors.
Table 3
Mediating effect of applications in the relationship between ideology and natural disaster prevention
Variables
|
|
Occurrence of natural disasters
|
(1)
|
(2)
|
(3)
|
(4)
|
Right
|
2.155
(2.381)
|
|
|
|
Left
|
|
0.057***
(0.040)
|
|
|
Center
|
|
|
0.362
(0.907)
|
|
Without orientation
|
|
|
|
18.413***
(15.514)
|
Application
|
1.979***
|
1.769***
|
1.912***
|
2.281***
|
|
(0.116)
|
(0.087)
|
(0.107)
|
(0.167)
|
Interaction
|
0.947
(0.115)
|
|
|
|
Interaction
|
|
1.407***
(0.111)
|
|
|
Interaction
|
|
|
1.217
(0.327)
|
|
Interaction
|
|
|
|
0.669***
(0.061)
|
GDP
|
0.542***
|
0.557***
|
0.551***
|
0.558***
|
|
(0.041)
|
(0.038)
|
(0.033)
|
(0.033)
|
GDP Growth
|
0.988
|
0.988
|
0.986
|
0.990
|
|
(0.012)
|
(0.014)
|
(0.013)
|
(0.013)
|
Density
|
1.041
|
1.044
|
1.039
|
1.084*
|
|
(0.050)
|
(0.044)
|
(0.040)
|
(0.049)
|
Human capital
|
0.808
|
0.846
|
0.767**
|
0.773**
|
|
(0.116)
|
(0.105)
|
(0.096)
|
(0.098)
|
Unemployment
|
0.984*
|
0.980**
|
0.986
|
0.984
|
|
(0.010)
|
(0.009)
|
(0.010)
|
(0.010)
|
Constante
|
0.400*
|
0.830
|
0.539
|
0.112***
|
|
(0.204)
|
(0.387)
|
(0.312)
|
(0.080)
|
Observations
|
1,851
|
1,851
|
1,851
|
1,851
|
Time dummy
|
yes
|
yes
|
yes
|
yes
|
Log -likelihood
|
-1253
|
-1253
|
-1253
|
-1253
|
LR Chi2
|
379.6
|
424.3
|
370.4
|
595.8
|
Prob Chi2
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
Pseudo R-squared
|
0.157
|
0.162
|
0.163
|
0.178
|
Note: The numbers in brackets represent standard deviations. ***, **, * represent the significance levels of 1 %, 5 % et 10 %. Source : Authors.
For the case of applications, the results are similar in terms of the effect on natural disaster prevention (Table 3). Indeed, the coefficients of this variable are all significant and greater than unity. Thus, the application of the application allows for an improvement in disaster prevention. Turning to the interaction variable, let us observe its coefficients. We see that this coefficient is significant only for Left-wing governments and those without an ideology in the case of patents and applications (Columns 2 and 4 of the tables 2 and 3). In other words, in a context of strong innovation, Left governments tend to be better at preventing natural disasters. In contrast, the result is the opposite for non-ideological countries. As we have shown in the correlation analysis, the reducing effect in non-ideological governments can be explained by the fact that they are mostly located in low disaster risk areas.
Table 4
Marginal effects of government ideology on prevention conditional on innovation
|
(1)
|
(2)
|
(3)
|
Variables
|
Right
|
Left
|
Center
|
Low level of innovation for patents
|
0.124**
|
-0.059
|
0.275**
|
|
(0.049)
|
(0.038)
|
(0.112)
|
High level of innovation for patents
|
-0.050
|
0.196***
|
-0.026
|
|
(0.066)
|
(0.046)
|
(0.092)
|
Observations
|
1,473
|
1,473
|
1,473
|
Low demand for applications
|
0.003
|
-0.006**
|
-0.002
|
|
(0.005)
|
(0.003)
|
(0.004)
|
High demand for applications
|
-0.001
|
0.065***
|
0.044**
|
|
(0.027)
|
(0.020)
|
(0.020)
|
Observations
|
1,851
|
1,851
|
1,851
|
Note: The numbers in brackets represent standard deviations. ***, **, * represent the significance levels of 1 %, 5 % et 10 %. Source: Authors.
The analysis of the interaction coefficients shows us that Left governments are more likely to prevent natural disasters when innovation is taken into account. However, in the correlation analysis we found that the relationship between the concepts could be positive when the level of innovation increases. In the tables 4 containing the average effects specific to the relationship between government ideology and prevention, we observe two trends conditional on innovation. For low levels of innovation (corresponding to a very low number of patents) the effect of government ideology worsens prevention against natural disasters, especially for the Right and Center governments (columns 1 and 3). We observe that this result seems to be significant in the context of applications for Left governments (column 2 table 4). On the other hand, when the level of innovation becomes high (corresponding to a high level of patents) the effect of ideology worsens disaster prevention only for Left governments (column 2).
This analysis can also be done by looking at the conditional effects graph for each type of innovation. On the graphs 2 and 3. We can see that the evolution of the marginal effects for patents and applications tends to be insignificant when the number of patents and applications increases for the Right and Centre governments. On the other hand, we observe that the curve seems to bend slightly for the case of patents (graph 2), before tending significantly towards a probability equal to unity. This result shows that the increase in the number of patents increases the probability of occurrence of natural disasters. As a result, they worsen prevention in Left governments. For the case of applications, the effect seems to stabilise towards a probability close to 0 when these applications are less than 6 in Left governments (graph 3). This shows that there may be a threshold at which innovation is detrimental to disaster prevention in developing countries.
For the control variables in the tables 2 and 3, the results are broken down as follows. In the different models in the tables 2 and 3, GDP has odds ratios below unity and significant at the 1% level. This suggests that, according to the different variations of government ideology, income level allows people to reduce the effects of natural disasters on their well-being. This supports the idea of Kahn (2005) and Kellenberg and Mobarak (2008) that income is a significant determinant of disaster risk reduction. The agglomeration factor measured here by population density has a coefficient greater than 1 and is significant at the thresholds (10% and 1%) in the table 2 and at the 10% threshold in the table 3 in column 4. This result shows that the population in the countries in our sample is not concentrated in areas at risk. This reduces government ownership in certain areas. This justifies a negative effect of the density variable on the occurrence of natural disasters. As for the human capital index, it has a hazard ratio below unity and significant at the threshold of 1% in all the model in the table 2. While in the table 3 the coefficient is significant at the 5% level in models 3 and 4. According to Tselios and Tompkins (2020), countries with low levels of education tend to have a higher probability of experiencing natural disasters. Finally, low unemployment is associated with low poverty. This leads to the abandonment by the population of the areas at risk.
6.2 Robutsness analysis
To test the robustness of the mediating effects, we use an alternative measure of innovation. This is total factor productivity. It is an indicator of technological change and innovation (Tselios and Tompkins, 2019, 2020). It is the growth in output that cannot be explained by changes in the quantity of inputs. This productivity is generally associated with the competitiveness ofan economy. By first conducting a correlation analysis between our three concepts[5], we obtain almost similar patterns to the same correlation analysis for the basic measures of innovation. In the annexed graph 4, countries without political ideology have the highest level of total factor productivity. A plausible explanation for this correlation is that, when looking at most countries without an ideology, one realises that their income comes mainly from the exploitation of natural resources. Most of these exploitations are carried out by foreign firms that import their technology. If we look at the correlation between total factor productivity and the probability of natural disasters, we find that it is initially positive for very low values of productivity. However, this relationship changes direction when total factor productivity reaches (1). This seems to support our basic analysis of innovation.
In the table 5, the different ways of validating the estimation technique are conclusive. The probability of the likelihood ratio test is below the conventional threshold of 1%. This allows us to reject the null hypothesis of null coefficients of the explanatory variables. Moreover, the pseudo R-squared tends to be very low, hence the validation of the goodness of fit of the model. Econometrically, our results show that both Right and Left governments have significant coefficients at the conventional 1 per cent level. This means that Right-wing governments are 6.225 times more likely to prevent natural disasters than other government ideology modalities. In contrast, Left-wing governments are 0.227 times less likely to prevent natural disasters than other modalities of government ideology. These findings are similar to those obtained in the baseline analysis for mediating effects. We also observe that the coefficient on the factor productivity variable is less than unity for the Left and Center governments.
Table 5
Mediating effect of total factor productivity in the relationship between ideology and disaster prevention
Variables
|
(1)
|
(2)
|
(3)
|
Right
|
6.225***
(4.289)
|
|
|
Left
|
|
0.227***
(0.114)
|
|
Center
|
|
|
0.851
(0.942)
|
Total factor productivity
|
0.678
|
0.372***
|
0.523***
|
|
(0.181)
|
(0.105)
|
(0.116)
|
Interaction
|
0.222**
(0.157)
|
|
|
Interaction
|
|
7.978***
(4.397)
|
|
Interaction
|
|
|
2.615
(3.047)
|
GDP
|
0.934
|
0.955
|
0.981
|
|
(0.053)
|
(0.061)
|
(0.057)
|
GDP Growth
|
1.028**
|
1.022**
|
1.024**
|
|
(0.013)
|
(0.010)
|
(0.011)
|
Density
|
0.980
|
0.991
|
0.986
|
|
(0.035)
|
(0.036)
|
(0.035)
|
Human capital
|
1.370***
|
1.411***
|
1.270**
|
|
(0.138)
|
(0.163)
|
(0.137)
|
Unemployment
|
0.983**
|
0.977**
|
0.983**
|
|
(0.008)
|
(0.009)
|
(0.008)
|
Constant
|
0.761
|
1.032
|
0.778
|
|
(0.288)
|
(0.446)
|
(0.287)
|
Observations
|
2,138
|
2,138
|
2,138
|
Time dummy
|
yes
|
yes
|
yes
|
Log -likelihood
|
-1378
|
-1378
|
-1378
|
LR Chi12
|
104.2
|
190.9
|
125.1
|
Prob Chi2
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
Pseudo R-squared
|
0.0338
|
0.0410
|
0.0359
|
Note: The numbers in brackets represent standard deviations. ***, **, * represent the significance levels of 1 %, 5 % et 10 %. Source: Authors.
Looking closely at the interaction terms, we find that only the coefficient of the interaction term between Left-wing government and total factor productivity is significant at the 1% level and above unity. Thus, for acceptable levels of total factor productivity, Left governments are able to prevent the risk of natural disasters. This result is similar to the one obtained in the baseline analysis. This result can also be confirmed by the analysis of the marginal effects table. Indeed, in the table 6 we observe that for low levels of total factor productivity only Left governments manage to implement measures that can prevent natural disasters. While in Right-wing governments the effect is the opposite. As the level of total factor productivity rises, right-wing governments catch up in disaster prevention. Left-wing governments, on the other hand, become lax in prevention. Similar conclusions can be drawn from the graph showing the evolution of marginal effects in the appendix. There is thus a threshold at which innovation undermines disaster prevention in left-wing governments.
Table 6
Marginal effects of government ideology on prevention conditional on total factor productivity
|
(1)
|
(2)
|
(3)
|
Variables
|
Right
|
Left
|
Center
|
Low level of total factor productivity
|
0.345***
|
-0.235***
|
0.007
|
|
(0.117)
|
(0.079)
|
(0.210)
|
High level of total factor productivity
|
-0.169**
|
0.612***
|
0.416
|
|
(0.084)
|
(0.127)
|
(0.342)
|
Observations
|
2,138
|
2,138
|
2,138
|
Note: The numbers in brackets represent standard deviations. ***, **, * represent the significance levels of 1 %, 5 % et 10 %. Source: Authors.
[4] It is a ratio of the probability of an event occurring in persons or traits susceptible to an event, and the probability of an event occurring in persons or traits not susceptible to an event.
[5] This involves correlating government ideology with total factor productivity and then correlating total factor productivity with the probability of occurrence of natural disasters.