3.1 Performance measures
We use several performance measures to capture the effects of ownership structure on firm performance. These measures include accounting-based (backward-looking measures), stock return, growth, and valuation (forward-looking measures). Additionally, we introduce a new measure of corporate governance. All these measures have been widely used in the literature.10 We want to determine whether there is a link between governance and ownership structure, which in turn might affect performance. In other words, we investigate whether ownership structure contributes to better corporate governance, and thus to better performance.
The accounting profitability measures we use are return on assets (ROA), return on sales (ROS), and earnings per share (EPS). ROA captures the firm’s profit from using its resources (total assets). Therefore, it is a direct measure of firm efficiency. The ratio is
$$ROA= \frac{Net income}{Total assets}$$
1
ROS captures the firm’s profit on its sales. We calculate it as
$$ROS= \frac{Net income}{Total sales}$$
2
The earnings per share is
$$EPS= \frac{Net income}{Outstanding shares}$$
3
We use sales growth (SG) as the growth measure. SG captures the increase in sales over time and provides an indirect measure of companies’ expansion (Bracker, Keats, and Pearson, 1988), which we calculate as
$$SG= \frac{{Sales}_{t}- {Sales}_{t-1}}{{Sales}_{t-1}}$$
4
We also use Tobin’ s Q as the valuation measure. This is a widely used measure in the literature as a direct measure of the increase in a firm’s value. Tobin’s Q is the ratio of the total equity value relative to the asset replacement cost. Because the replacement cost is difficult to calculate, we proxy it by total assets. Therefore, we calculate Tobin’s Q as
$${Tobin Q}_{ i}= \frac{{Market cap.}_{i}}{{Total assets}_{i}}$$
5
Moreover, we use governance scores as an indirect measure of firm performance. Some authors argue that better corporate governance contributes to better firm performance (Gompers et al. 2004; Bhagat and Bolton, 2008). Here, we aim to uncover the potential relationship between governance and ownership that might lead to enhanced firm performance.11
For stock returns, we use the annual holding period returns (HPR), which we calculate for each company over the five-year sample period as
$${HPR}_{i}={\left[\left(1+ {R}_{i1}\right)*\left(1+ {R}_{i2}\right)*\dots .* \left(1+ {R}_{it}\right)\right]}^{1/t}-1$$
6
where t represents time and R represents the annual raw returns calculated for each company i for each year as:
$${R}_{i}= \frac{{Dividend}_{i}+ \left({Ending price}_{i}-{Beginning price}_{i}\right)}{{Beginning price}_{i}}$$
7
The yearly raw returns, R, are adjusted with the TASI general market index for the corresponding period. Thus, the adjusted return AR is
$${AR}_{i}= {HPR}_{i}-TASI$$
8
Therefore, we report both the raw HPR and the AR.
3.2 Ownership classifications and performance
Owners vary in their ability to monitor management. The general public, which typically holds the largest portion of shares, is the weakest, dispersed, and has no control over the firm. By contrast, institutional investors typically hold smaller stakes, but usually represent a blockholder with superior power and possess strong control over the firm. Additionally, owners may have different goals. Some investors, such as the government, might pursue social and economic goals, and not necessarily profitability, while the goal of other owners might be to maximize share value. Consequently, differentiating between these groups is imperative.
La Porta et al. (1999), in their seminal work on corporate ownership worldwide, classify companies into six categories: widely held, family, state, widely held financial, widely held corporation, and miscellaneous. They use arbitrary cutoffs of 10% and 20% to identify the ultimate owners of the largest 20 firms in 27 rich nations.12 Our approach differs in that we do not impose a cutoff because it might be misleading in identifying the real ultimate owners. For example, a cutoff of 10% or 20% will exclude many firms with blockholders of 5%. Instead, we review each company individually to identify the ultimate owner/s.
We divide firms into six classes: (1) public firms, (2) government, (3) institutional, (4) managerial, (5) family, and (6) foreign. Furthermore, we allow for multiple classifications if the companies have more than one ultimate owner.
Public firms are widely held corporations in which the general public owns all or most of the shares without any single controlling blockholder. These firms are generally managed and controlled by the board of directors and management, without substantial management ownership. Government firms are corporations in which government entities own the largest aggregate portion of shares and/or if a government entity represents a blockholder with ownership of \(\ge 5\%\). We classify corporate owners as institutional if the combination of both corporate and/or mutual fund holdings represent the greatest number of holdings and/or the firm has an institutional blockholder with holdings of \(\ge 5\%\). Managerial firms are those that are owned completely by the general public, similar to the public firms, but differ in that an individual or individuals hold a blockholding portion and/or serve on the board. Family firms are corporations that are 100% family business pre-IPO, and in which family members still have a large portion of the stocks in the post-IPO period, and/or family members serve on the board. Foreign firms are corporations in which strategic foreign partners own a blockholding percentage of shares, and/or the company’ s total foreign holdings exceed 10% of outstanding shares.
Figure 1 depicts all six types of owners, including an example with multiple-classifications. Figure 1 (g) shows a company that is classified as both managerial and institutional. The company clearly has an individual owner with holdings of 20.3% of the outstanding shares and an executive role on the board. Thus, this company is a managerial firm. Additionally, the company’s greatest holding is for institutions, at 62.37% (combination of both corporates and mutual funds). One of these companies is Savola, which holds only 49%. Thus, the company is also an institutional firm.
Figure 1 (h) presents a more interesting case of multiple classifications for Bank Alrajhi, which is the largest bank in Saudi Arabia. This bank was a family business for the Alrajhi family, which still holds 2.16% and holds the board Chairperson position.13 Therefore, we classify this company as a family firm. At the same time, institutional holdings represent the largest group of owners, at 43.61% (24.61% for corporations and 20% for mutual funds). Thus, we can classify it as an institutional firm as well. Further, the General Organization for Social and Insurance (GOSI), a government entity, holds a blockholding portion at 5.86% and has a representative on the board. We thus also classify the bank as a government-owned firm. Thus, we classify bank Alrajhi as a family, institutional, and government-owned firm at the same time.
Then, we compare and contrast the six ownership types in terms of profitability, valuation, growth, stock returns, and governance. We use a matched pairs approach to compare each group’s average with the other groups’ average. We aim to determine if we can draw any conclusions from this comparison; that is, we want to know if companies with different ownership concentrations perform differently.
Furthermore, we use the 20% cutoff classification approach in La Porta et al. (1999) and divide companies into four categories: public firms, government, institutional, and foreign. In this method, we classify our 174 listed firms according to the dominant (ultimate) owner. Under these criteria, we apply the following rules:
-
Public companies: Firms with no dominant owner (blockholder) with holdings > 20%.
-
Government companies: the aggregate holdings of government entities are 20% or more and represent the largest owners.
-
Institutional companies: the aggregate holdings of institutions are 20% or more and they represent the largest owner.
-
Foreign firms: the aggregate foreign holdings are 20% or more and they are the largest owner.
Therefore, each company will fall within one ultimate owner classification, and no multiple classifications are allowed. Figure 3 shows examples of each of the four classes.
We also compare and contrast the performance of these groups to see if we can draw any conclusions. We also use this method to check the results of the first classification comparison results.
3.3 Theoretical framework and model setup.
We propose two models to investigate the association between ownership and performance. In the first model, we assume an exogenous relationship, and in the second model, we assume an endogenous relationship. Assuming an exogenous relationship, we employ the following two single equations:
Firm performance = f {Government ownership; institutional (corporates, mutual funds); public ownership; foreign ownership; family; size; age; financial; risk, governance score} | (9) |
Ownership = f {Performance; public ownership; institutional ownership; foreign ownership; family; size; age; financial, risk, governance score} | (10) |
We measure firm performance using the log (Tobin’s Q) and adjusted returns alternately. We examine various ownership classes and use several control variables. First, we include government ownership, which is the percentage of government entity holdings of total shares. Government ownership represents 20% of the total ownership in 27 nations (La Porta et al. 1999). In Saudi Arabia, the government holds 20.3% of total shares and almost 40% by market value.
Some studies argue that state ownership is inefficient and bureaucratic (Shleifer and Vishny, 1994; Stulz, 1988). Many governments, particularly in the west, conducted large-scale privatization in the 1970s and 1980s, believing that privatization would reduce government involvement in the market and consequently enhance the free market. The main argument for the inefficiency of state ownership pertains to the divergence between control rights and cash flow rights. Control rights are concentrated among politicians, and cash flows and profits are allocated back to the company or to the national budget. This discourages managers from pursuing profit maximization strategies. Megginson, Nash, and Randenborgh (1994) examine 61 privatized firms across 32 industries from 18 countries. They conclude that government ownership is inefficient compared to private ownership, finding that all privatized corporations became more profitable, increased their sales, and become more efficient, without sacrificing jobs.14
On the other hand, government ownership can save the market from failure and eliminate monopolies. The tendency worldwide after the global financial crisis (GFC, 2008) is towards nationalization. Sun, Tong, and Tong (2002) find a positive effect of government ownership on firm performance among Chinese listed firms. In Saudi Arabia (a monarchy system), we would expect the government to exert even stronger power and influence. Saudi government ownership is concentrated, particularly in successful large companies and strategic industries such as the petrochemical and energy sectors. Therefore, we hypothesize a positive relationship between government ownership and performance.
The second independent variable is institutional ownership. We break institutional ownership into two components (corporates and mutual funds) to allow for variations between the two parties. Prior studies argue that institutional investors are more sophisticated and informed than other investors. Taylor (1990) documents the increasing importance of institutional investors in the US, where the equity held by institutions increased dramatically, from only 8% in 1950 to 45% by 1990. The expected effect of institutional investors on corporate performance is supported by the active monitoring argument. In this argument, institutional investors are better qualified, more active, and more informed than the general public to monitor management. In addition, institutional investors have the ability to take necessary action against management, and therefore watch managers more effectively and with less cost (Hand, 1990). Hartzell and Starks (2003) find that the level of management compensation is negatively related to the degree of institutional ownership, which indicates that institutional investors can mitigate agency problems at lower costs than in the absence of institutional investors.
McConnell and Servaes (1990) investigate 1,173 companies for 1976 and another 1,093 companies for 1986 and document a positive relationship between firm value, measured by Tobin’s Q, and institutional ownership. Yuan et al. (2008) examine 1,211 Chinese firms between 2001 and 2005 and find that mutual funds contribute positively to firm performance.
Nevertheless, not all arguments are in favor of institutional investors, and some empirical evidence suggests a negative effect. The institutional myopia argument states that institutional investors usually focus on short-term objectives and fast returns, which make them pressure management to pursue unjustifiable projects. Wahal (1996) finds evidence for the argument that institutional investors have a positive effect on firm performance only for the short term. The author examines the impact of pension funds on firm performance, as measured by both accounting profitability and stock returns, and finds no positive effect.
Another argument to explain the negative impact of institutional investors is the strategic-alignment conflict of interest proposed by Pound (1988). In this explanation, institutional investors cooperate with and support managers, instead of providing effective monitoring of interpersonal business relationships because the benefits of cooperating are larger than effective monitoring gains15.
Nevertheless, institutional investors’ stake in the Saudi market grew rapidly, jumping from 20% to over 30% in five years. We posit that institutional investors in Saudi Arabia would have the same impact as the government, and we thus expect a positive link.
In addition, we include public ownership as an independent variable as the third explanatory variable. Jensen and Meckling (1976) propose a positive impact of diffused ownership on performance because combining the incentives for managers and dispersed shareholders might reduce agency problems. Benston (1985) examines the effect of dispersed shareholders on 29 large corporations between 1970 and 1975, and concludes that the officer-directors of large companies hold a sufficiently large amount of shares to have an incentive to make decisions that increase the market value of the company for the benefit of all. In addition, Byrd et al. (1998) support the positive effect of dispersed ownership on firm performance.
On the contrary, several arguments suggest a negative effect of managerial ownership on corporate performance. Firms with dispersed ownership have no large blockholders, and are controlled by managers (insiders). According to information asymmetry theory, managers may exploit the company in the absence of large investors. Fama and Jensen (1983b) propose a “hold-up” problem, in which shareholders cannot prevent opportunistic behavior by managers even though they recognize it. Morck et al. (1988) and Stulz (1988) call this opportunistic behavior managerial entrenchment, meaning that management can undertake projects that cannot be justified from a reward/risk rationale. In Saudi Arabia, only a few companies are widely held. We anticipate a negative effect of public ownership on performance.
Moreover, we add foreign ownership as an independent variable. With the rise of globalization, the importance of foreign ownership is attracting a lot of attention from both academicians and policy makers. The question to answer here is whether foreign ownership leads to better firm performance. Grant (1987) finds that foreign ownership leads to better firm profitability in the UK. Qian (1998) analyzes foreign ownership among American industrial firms over a ten-year period and concludes that foreign ownership has a significant positive impact on firm performance.16
On the contrary, Kim and Lyn (1990) associate foreign ownership with negative performance. The authors find that firms with foreign ownership perform worse than their counterparts without foreign holdings. Similarly, Driffield and Girma (2003) find a negative impact of foreign ownership on firm performance due to the higher wages that foreign firms pay, which offset productivity. Brennan and Cao (1997) suggest that foreign investors suffer considerable disadvantages compared to local investors due to their lack of knowledge and expertise in the domestic market. In Saudi Arabia, the market authority is offering many initiatives to attract foreign investors. The Saudi Tadawul is now included in the FTSI Russell emerging market index. However, because all these changes are recent, we cannot predict the effect of foreign ownership.
We also include the family ownership variable as a dummy variable equal to one if the company is a family firm and zero otherwise.17 Family ownership is the most common type worldwide. La Porta, Lopez, and Shleifer (1999) and La Porta, Lopez, Shleifer, and Vishny (2000) find that family owned firms are the most common type in 27 countries. Moreover, Anderson and Reeb (2003) find that more than one-third of S&P 500 firms are owned by families. Their findings reveal a positive impact of family ownership, with family controlled firms outperforming non-family controlled firms. The authors also find that the relationship between family ownership and performance is non-linear, which is similar to dispersed ownership.
Maury (2006) considers 1,672 companies from Western European countries, finding that family controlled firms have better profitability rates than do non-family controlled firms. Nevertheless, the author documents a conflict between family managers and minority shareholders in the absence of shareholder protection in some countries. Moreover, Andres (2008) examines 275 German listed corporations and finds that family firms are not only more profitable than are widely held dispersed firms, but also outperform companies with other types of blockholders. However, this positive effect on firm performance is conditional on the presence of family members on the companies’ boards. Another argument for the positive effect of family ownership, besides the alignment of interests argument, includes the long-term orientation of the family owner.
In contrast, several studies document a negative effect of family ownership on corporate performance. Villalonga and Amit (2006) examine data on Fortune 500 firms in the US from 1994 to 2000, finding that family ownership adds value to the firm only when the founder serves as CEO or as the board Chairperson. In other words, family ownership has a positive impact on the prevalence of family founders in the firm. A study by Klein, Shapiro, and Young (2005) on 263 Canadian listed firms measured the relationship between various governance indices and ownership structures, and firm performance. They find strong evidence suggesting that family ownership has a negative effect on corporate performance, as measured by Tobin’s Q.
The major argument for the negative effect of family ownership on firm performance pertains to private control benefits. In this argument, the conflict between the family owner and dispersed shareholders increases with increased family holdings, especially in countries characterized by low minority shareholder protection. This effect is even more evident when family owners are involved in management, which discourages qualified managers from improving firm efficiency, known as the manager discouragement argument (Smith and Amoako-Adu, 1999).
In Saudi Arabia, about 11% of the listed companies are family owned, even though family members do not seem to hold large stakes any longer. These family members have a strong presence in the board, hold executive roles, hold shares, and some remain hidden by holding less than the 5% threshold of shares. We conjecture a negative effect of family ownership due to increased agency costs.
Other common control variables include company size (log of market value), age (number of years from establishment year to the year 2018), financial (a dummy equal to one if the company operates in the banking or insurance industry and zero otherwise), risk in terms of the volatility of returns (the standard deviation of returns), and the governance score a control variable to examine whether better governance leads to better performance.
In the second equation (Eq. 10), we replace the dependent variable (firm performance) with ownership, and use firm performance as an explanatory variable. We examine the causality as we do not know which factor is the driving force. We use the same explanatory variables as explained above.
Recent studies, however, consider ownership as endogenous to performance, as opposed to the traditional assumption of exogenous ownership (Demsetz and Lehn, 1985). Thus, it is challenging to identify which construct is the driving force. This led to three conclusions from the empirical evidence: the ownership–performance relationship is unidirectional, where ownership affects performance only; the relationship runs in reverse, where performance affects ownership only, or the relationship is bidirectional, where the effect runs in both directions.
The solution in the literature is to use either a 2-SLS regression for a single equation and to treat ownership as endogenous, or to use a 2-SLS simultaneous equations approach. We propose the following simultaneous equations model and estimate it using the 2-SLS approach.
Firm performance = f {Government ownership; institutional (corporates, mutual funds); public ownership; size; age; financial; family; risk; governance score} Government ownership = f {Firm performance; institutional (corporate); public ownership; size; age; risk; governance score} Public ownership = f {Firm performance; government ownership; size; age; governance score} | (11) |
In this system, we have three dependent variables: firm performance, government ownership, and public ownership. The explanatory variables are the same as those explained earlier. We verify the ranking of the system and test our choice of instrumental variables for the 2SLS estimation in terms of bias and consistency. The system is identified.