The study examines the impact on domestic production, household consumption, domestic prices, household welfare and major macroeconomic indicators.
5.1 Effect on domestic production
Table 3 depicts the change in domestic production because of increased TFP of water fetching and firewood collection activities and reduction of trade and transport margins. Domestic production increases in both scenarios. Specifically, production of water fetching on average increases by 18.9% and firewood collection on average increases by 18.8% due to enhanced TFP in the first scenario. Labor freed from water fetching and firewood collection is reallocated to agricultural, industry and services and stimulates production in the destination sector. Production of agriculture, industry and services on average increases by 0.5%, 1.8% and 0.1%, respectively in the first scenario.
The production of leisure increases by 2.4% in the first scenario, which is relatively greater than other sectors such as agriculture, industry, and services. This happens because there was less or no time left for leisure activities when household collects water and firewood from the distant sources and therefore, the freed labor prefers to enjoy leisure and hence more labors are reallocated to leisure. On the other hand, less trade and transport margins encourage larger supply of commodities to the market, and enhance domestic production. Production of agriculture, industry, service, water fetching, firewood collection and leisure increases by 0.1%, 0.3%, 0.8%, 12.5%, 12.5% and 1.6%, respectively in the second scenario. Since trade and transport margins are higher for non-agricultural commodities relative to agricultural commodities, the reduction of margins provides bigger incentives for non-agricultural production. For instance, industrial and service production increases by a larger proportion relative to other sectors in the second scenario.
Table 3
Simulated changes (percentage) in domestic production by sectors
Sector
|
Scenario one
|
Scenario two
|
Agricultural
|
0.54
|
0.09
|
Industry
|
1.77
|
0.26
|
Service
|
0.13
|
0.78
|
Water fetching
|
18.89
|
12.53
|
Firewood collection
|
18.84
|
12.47
|
Leisure
|
2.37
|
1.64
|
Source: Author’s computation based on model results |
5.2 Effect on domestic consumption
The labor reallocated to other sectors enhances domestic production (Table 3) and at the same time results in higher income for households. The freed labor from fetching water and firewood and subsequently reallocated to other sectors brings extra income to the households which increases household consumption demand (QCD). The extra income results an upward shift in household’s consumption demand. Table 4 describes the percentage change (weighted) in QCD. The QCD increases for all commodities in the first scenario. Specifically, the QCD for HPHC (home production for home consumption) food, HPHC non-food, market food and market non-food commodities increase by 0.7%, 3.9%, 0.3% and 0.9%, respectively in the first scenario. Since water fetching and firewood commodities are categorized under HPHC non-food, the consumption of these commodities are higher relative to other commodities in the first scenario.
On the other hand, lower trade and transport margins makes marketed commodities relatively cheaper and hence household consumption increases. Household demand for marketed commodities increases in the second scenario: by 0.2% for market food and by 1% for market non-food commodities. Trade and transport margins constitute a higher share of the cost of marketed non-food commodities in comparison to marketed food commodities. Therefore, due to less trade and transport margins, consumption of marketed non-food commodities increases more compared to marketed food commodities.
Table 4
Simulated changes (percentage) in household consumption demand (QCD)
Commodities
|
Scenario one
|
Scenario two
|
HPHC food
|
0.73
|
0.25
|
HPHC non-food
|
3.97
|
0.58
|
Market food
|
0.25
|
0.16
|
Market non-food
|
0.91
|
1.04
|
Source: Author’s computation based on model results |
The policy simulations also influence consumption of HPHC commodities. Consumption of HPHC commodities increases in second scenario: by 0.3% in HPHC food and by 0.6% in HPHC non-food commodities. Although trade and transport margins do not directly affect HPHC commodities, the consumption of these commodities increase due to the income effect. Particularly, improved road infrastructure enhanced domestic production that led to increased household income and hence increased consumption of HPHC commodities.
5.3 Effect on domestic price
The freed labor from fetching water and firewood and reallocated to other sectors brings extra income to the households which increases household consumption demand (QCD and hence increases domestic prices (PQD). Table 5 describes the percentage change (weighted) in PQD in response to higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection and less trade and transport margin. In the first scenario the PQD for HPHC food, HPHC non-food, market food and market non-food commodities on average increase by 2%, 15.3%, 0.7% and 0.9%, respectively. This implies that effect of income increase dominates the price effect. The extra income results an upward shift in household’s consumption demand and hence increases domestic prices. The increases in price for HPHC non-food commodities are relatively higher because of a bigger upward shift for the demand for these commodities and hence their prices increase by the higher percentage.
On the other hand, improved access to road transport infrastructure mainly affects prices of marketed commodities. This is because these groups of commodities use the services of trade and transport. The decrease in trade and transport margins reduces the gap between consumer price and producer price. In the second scenario, due to less trade and transport margins, the PQD decrease by 0.9% and 0.6% for market food and market non-food commodities, respectively. However, the PQD for HPHC food and HPHC non-food commodities increase by 1.4% and 0.9%, respectively. Even though HPHC commodities are not directly affected by the second policy scenarios, the price for these commodities is influenced indirectly through the income effect.
Table 5
Simulated changes (percentage) in domestic price (PQD)
Commodities
|
Scenario one
|
Scenario two
|
HPHC food
|
2.00
|
1.36
|
HPHC non-food
|
15.25
|
0.89
|
Market food
|
0.70
|
-0.90
|
Market non-food
|
0.86
|
-0.60
|
Source: Author’s computation based on model results |
5.4 Effects on welfare
Increased TFP of water fetching and firewood collection and reduction of trade and transport margin also affects household welfare. Table 6 shows the equivalent variation (EV) in percent of base income to examine the actual welfare changes across household groups. Welfare improvement happens to all groups of households in both scenarios except non-poor households located in urban areas but the amount of welfare gain varies among households.
Different household groups allocate divergent quantities of labor for water fetching and firewood collection. Accordingly, the welfare gains in the first scenario depend on household endowment of labor that can be potentially allocated to water fetching and firewood collection. In other words, households that allocate a relatively larger proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection obtain high welfare gains. For instance, non-poor and poor rural households in agro-ecology zones 1 and 5 allocate the highest proportion of labor to water fetching and firewood collection relative to other groups of households. Because of increase in the TFP of water fetching and firewood collection, welfare gains by these household groups are higher than other groups of households.
On the other hand, welfare gains in the second scenario are driven by the increase in the consumption of households in response to less trade and transport margins and hence lower price. Households that consume a larger proportion of market non-food commodities are relatively better off than other households are. This is because the cost of margin services accounts for a relatively high proportion of the total expenditure of market non-food commodities. Accordingly, lower trade and transport margins strongly increase the consumption of market non-food commodities and hence contribute to the well-being of households.
However, the welfare of urban non-poor households is negatively affected in both scenarios. This can be explained by the fact that financing the construction of water facility, energy technology and road infrastructure are obtained from government savings that are raised through income tax. Since urban non-poor households contribute a larger share of tax to the government, their consumption expenditure decreases and hence welfare declines.
Table 6
Simulated changes (percentage) in household welfare (EV/base income)
Households
|
Scenario one
|
Scenario two
|
Household rural zone 1 poor agricultural
|
3.64
|
0.84
|
Household rural zone 1 poor mixed
|
3.64
|
0.84
|
Household rural zone 1 poor non-agricultural
|
3.64
|
0.84
|
Household rural zone 2 poor agricultural
|
3.15
|
1.38
|
Household rural zone 2 poor mixed
|
3.15
|
1.38
|
Household rural zone 2 poor non-agricultural
|
3.15
|
1.38
|
Household rural zone 3 poor agricultural
|
3.42
|
1.44
|
Household rural zone 3 poor mixed
|
3.42
|
1.44
|
Household rural zone 3 poor non-agricultural
|
3.42
|
1.44
|
Household rural zone 4 poor agricultural
|
3.17
|
1.28
|
Household rural zone 4 poor mixed
|
3.17
|
1.28
|
Household rural zone 4 poor non-agricultural
|
3.17
|
1.28
|
Household rural zone 5 poor agricultural
|
3.59
|
0.80
|
Household rural zone 5 poor mixed
|
3.59
|
0.80
|
Household rural zone 5 poor non-agricultural
|
3.59
|
0.80
|
Household rural zone 1 non-poor agricultural
|
3.06
|
0.97
|
Household rural zone 1 non-poor mixed
|
3.06
|
0.97
|
Household rural zone 1 non-poor non-agricultural
|
3.06
|
0.97
|
Household rural zone 2 non-poor agricultural
|
2.19
|
1.02
|
Household rural zone 2 non-poor mixed
|
2.19
|
1.02
|
Household rural zone 2 non-poor non-agricultural
|
2.19
|
1.02
|
Household rural zone 3 non-poor agricultural
|
2.63
|
1.23
|
Household rural zone 3 non-poor mixed
|
2.63
|
1.23
|
Household rural zone 3 non-poor non-agricultural
|
2.63
|
1.23
|
Household rural zone 4 non-poor agricultural
|
2.40
|
1.13
|
Household rural zone 4 non-poor mixed
|
2.40
|
1.13
|
Household rural zone 4 non-poor non-agricultural
|
2.40
|
1.13
|
Household rural zone 5 non-poor agricultural
|
3.13
|
0.71
|
Household rural zone 5 non-poor mixed
|
3.13
|
0.71
|
Household rural zone 5 non-poor non-agricultural
|
3.13
|
0.71
|
Household small urban poor
|
1.59
|
1.08
|
Household big urban poor
|
1.63
|
0.77
|
Household small urban non-poor
|
-6.60
|
-6.93
|
Household big urban non-poor
|
-3.54
|
-3.83
|
Source: Author’s computation based on model results |
5.5 Macroeconomic effects
Increase TFP of water fetching and firewood collection and reduction of trade and transport margins creates economy-wide linkages and positively affects the macroeconomic indicators such as GDP, total domestic production, absorption, import, export and exchange rate. Table 7 depicts the macroeconomic effect of higher TFP in water fetching and firewood collection and less trade and transport margins.
Total domestic production increases by 1.4%, private consumption by 1.7%, GDP by 1.5%, absorption by 1.3% and import by 0.1% in the first scenario. The released labor from water fetching and firewood collection is reallocated to productive sectors that accelerate domestic production. This leads to an increase in domestic consumption (absorption) and import. Furthermore, reallocated labor promotes the growth of the economy and hence the GDP increases.
On the other hand, in the second scenario GDP increases by 0.2%, private consumption by 0.1%, investment consumption by 1%, absorption by 0.2%, total domestic production by 0.2% and import demand by 0.1%. Improved road infrastructure facilitates trade and transport activities in the economy that enhance transportation of commodities into the market and results low prices of commodities. This leads to an increases in domestic demand and hence more domestic production that accelerate the growth of the economy and increases GDP.
Table 7
Real macroeconomic effects (percentage changes)
Real macroeconomic indicators
|
Scenario one
|
Scenario two
|
Private consumption
|
1.67
|
0.05
|
Investment consumption
|
0.38
|
0.96
|
Absorption
|
1.34
|
0.16
|
Import
|
0.08
|
0.10
|
GDP
|
1.54
|
0.18
|
Total domestic production
|
1.35
|
0.24
|
Source: Author’s computation based on model results |